Topic 1: The Nature and Functions of Money


Our concern in this Lesson is with the causes of inflation. We will show that the cause of all major inflations is excess expansion of the money supply. To begin, we must deal with the question of why money exists in the first place. Here we expand on the analysis presented in the Lesson called The Dimensions of Economic Activity.

To understand why people hold money, imagine what life would be like without it. Suppose that people hold no cash and have no bank deposits that they can transfer to others by writing cheques. You go into McDonalds to purchase a hamburger. How are you going to pay for it? At a wage rate of $10 per hour, probably the best method of payment is to wash dishes for 25 minutes. But if you are a lawyer, this might be embarrassing, although you might be able to persuade the franchise owner to accept 3 minutes of legal advice. Moreover, as a lawyer, how are you going to charge people for your services? Presumably they would have to supply you with appropriate goods and services in return.

Without money, exchange between individuals has to take the form of barter. The problem with barter is that it requires the double coincidence of wants---each party to the exchange must want to sell what the other wants to buy. In the absence of money, an enormous fraction of people's time and effort will be used up making exchange by pursuing and arranging barter opportunities---this would drastically reduce the time available to produce goods and services that can be consumed or invested.

But why can't the double coincidence problem of barter be avoided by a system of loans or credits cleared through a clearing house? For example, the CCSMT (Community of Churches, Synagogues, Mosques and Temples), a morally impeccable social service group, could offer to clear private exchanges every month. A particular commodity could be designated a numeraire, and all individuals would simply note all sums owing to them for end-of-month clearance. The first problem with such a system is that the services of religious groups and other social service organizations are not free---resources would required for the simple mechanics of clearing transactions and this would not be cheap, even in the era of modern computers. The other problem, of course, is that not everyone is honest. There would be no constraint on overspending one's income---or the implementation and enforcement of such a constraint would be very costly. To make exchange in this fashion, one would have to verify the credit-worthiness of every transactor dealt with. This would, be prohibitively expensive for small transactions, though not for purchase of major items like cars or houses. A credit-clearance system would thus be impractical even in traditional societies with strong cultural and religious controls. Something has always been used throughout history, not only as a unit of account, but as a medium of exchange. This is the basic function of money---to reduce the resource cost of making transactions.

Money is often viewed as having an additional function---to act as a store of value through time. In this respect, however, money is not special. Houses, cars, TV sets, clothes, and all other forms of capital are stores of value. Being a store of value simply designates money as a form of capital. The stock of money, like the stocks of buildings, machines, and human skills, is part of the economy's stock of capital. The output flow from money is the goods and services that can be produced with labour and capital that would otherwise have been tied up doing barter or checking people's credit-worthiness.

Historically, even primitive societies used some form of money. Precious metals---usually gold or silver---were typically the unit of account and medium of exchange until 100 years ago. In medieval times, kings and feudal lords minted gold (or silver) into coins to provide a standard for transactions--hence the term Gold Standard. As the financial system evolved it became inconvenient to hold actual gold coin and people would customarily deposit the gold for safe-keeping with a bank in return for bank-notes that the bank agreed to redeem for gold at any time. This paper money was as good as gold in the sense that it was freely convertible into gold coin. Then, instead of issuing bank notes, it became convenient for banks to give depositors accounts from which they could withdraw paper money, or gold, and on which they could write cheques that would transfer the funds to other people in payment for goods and services. The medium of exchange then consisted of not only gold coin and paper money, but bank deposits as well.

At this point problems arose when banks issued paper money that they subsequently were unable to redeem in gold on request. This led to government regulations on who could own banks and government monitoring of day-to-day bank operations. It was then but a short step for the government to assume responsibility for issuing all paper money---the government then assumed the obligation to redeem this paper money in gold on request.

The gold standard system evolved to the point where very few people held monetary gold---everyone operated with paper money, token coins (which like paper money were redeemable in gold) and bank deposits. Gold was the standard for the monetary system in the sense that all deposits and circulating media were convertible into gold on demand. This implied that, even though gold was not used in transactions, the total quantity of money in circulation (token coins, paper money and deposits) was limited by the quantity of gold held by the government as backing for it. The government had to maintain gold reserves in case someone wanted to convert paper money into gold. It had to provide gold backing for all the paper money it issued.

In a gold standard system of this sort, the only function of the link of paper money to gold is the limiting effect of available gold reserves on the quantity of money the government can issue. If the government is a trustworthy custodian of the money supply, resources can be saved by simply having the government issue and control the money supply directly, without any gold-reserve backing. Paper money would no longer be convertible into gold, but that would not matter because no one needs to hold monetary gold anyway. The supply of money in circulation is simply controlled directly by the government monetary authority. The advantage is that resources do not have to be wasted digging gold out of the ground for storage in government vaults.

How does the government control the money supply? In most countries, a government agency called the central bank is entrusted with responsibility for managing the money supply. This agency is usually somewhat independent of the government currently in power---this is to prevent politicians from using money creation to finance handouts to voters right before elections. The details of the process of money creation are complex and are covered thoroughly in a later Lesson, Monetary Policy Under Fixed Exchange Rates. The complexity arises because the banking system plays an important role in determining the money supply. This means that the central bank has to work harder to maintain the money supply at the desired level.

Since the complexities relating to the banking system are not relevant to the discussion that follows, we can ignore them here. The central bank can be thought of as having two avenues of money-supply control. First, it can buy and sell bonds from the private sector. This is called open market operations. When the bank buys bonds from the public, it gives money in return---that money is put into circulation. Similarly, by selling bonds to the private sector the central bank can take money out of circulation. A second way the central bank can increase the money supply is by purchasing bonds from other branches of government which then spend the money in the provision of government services---this money thus goes directly into circulation. This method of money creation is typically called the printing press. The government as a whole, which includes the central bank, is essentially borrowing from itself and spending the proceeds---it is as if the government simply prints money and spends it. The reason why countries make their central banks independent of the political electoral process is to prevent the government from borrowing from itself and printing money in this fashion. This independence is achieved by appointing central bank governors for long terms and not requiring them to be answerable to the currently elected prime minister or president. We will see the need for this more clearly in subsequent topics.

Essentially, the government faces a budget constraint of the sort

         G   =   T   +  ΔB/Δt   +  ΔM/Δt 

where  G  is government expenditure,  T  is the revenue from taxes,  B  is the public's holdings of government bonds  M  is the money supply, and  ΔB/Δt  and  ΔM/Δt refer to the change in the stocks of government bonds and money held by the public in the current time period. This says that the government must finance its expenditure by either levying taxes, selling bonds to the public or printing money and increasing the money stock. The government has to pay interest on bonds it sells, the stock of which represents the public debt. And no one wants to pay taxes! Printing money and spending it, on the other hand, appears on the surface to be rather painless. You will learn why printing money is also not a painless alternative in subsequent topics.

Before turning to the role of money in price level determination and in generating inflation, we need to think about how the quantity of money can be measured. Obviously, cash in people's hands is part of the money supply. So is the quantity of chequable deposits held in banks. Because cash and bank deposits can be used directly to acquire goods and services they are said to possess a quality called liquidity. In fact, cash is more liquid than bank deposits because cheques can bounce and are therefore a bit less acceptable than cash in making transactions---that is, they are not absolutely convertible into cash at all times and places.

Time deposits---that is, deposits that can be converted into cash by going to the bank or making a phone call but cannot be transferred by cheque---are also quite liquid and are sometimes counted as part of the money supply. Cash plus demand deposits are referred to as  M1  (the narrowest definition of money) and cash plus both demand and time deposits is called  M2.  An even broader definition of money, typically called  M3,  would include additional assets less directly usable for making exchange, such as short-term government bonds, etc.

There is no clear line separating money from non-monetary assets. And the quantities of different measures of the money supply sometimes move in opposite directions through time, making it difficult for central banks to conduct monetary policy. Clearly, however, corporate bonds, common stocks, mortgages, automobiles and houses, cannot be viewed as part of the money supply. Assets become increasingly less liquid as they become more difficult to convert quickly into a predictable amount of cash. Cars are thus less liquid than common stocks, houses are less liquid than cars, and shoes are even more illiquid.

It is now time for a test on this Topic. As always, commit yourself to an answer in every case before looking at the one provided.

Question 1
Question 2

Choose Another Topic in the Lesson