Topic 6. Intergenerational Transfers


We commonly hear it said that excess government borrowing is bad because we are placing a burden on future generations. We are enjoying additional consumption now, but our children will pay for it later on. This topic investigates the intergenerational effects of bond vs. tax finance of government expenditure. As in the previous topic we will assume that the government cuts taxes by $100 dollars and floats bonds, all of which are purchased by a segment of the population, called A-people. The remaining population, B-people, purchase no bonds.

Half of the population is composed of A-people and half of B-people. Each A-person purchases $200 of government debt and everyone gets a tax cut of $100. Taxes are paid in equal shares by everyone. At an assumed interest rate of 5 percent, everyone pays $5 of additional taxes in all future years and the A-people receive $10 in interest payments per year. As noted earlier, each A-person is, in effect, loaning $100 to a B-person. This is shown in the Table below.

  A-People   B-People
Current Year
 Tax Cut$100$100
 Bonds Purchased$2000
All Future Years
 Interest Received (at 5%)$100
 Tax Increase$5$5

The simple Ricardian Equivalence idea rests on the fact that all public debt must be serviced in perpetuity or paid back, so the future tax revenues raised to pay the interest on the debt must be equal in present value to the current tax cut. But this assumes that people live for ever.

Suppose that a particular B-person, who buys no bonds, knows he is going to die within a few years. At an interest rate of 5 percent, the present value of future tax increases that he will pay is much less than his $100 tax cut. If he lived only one year, for example, he would pay back only $5. His wealth has increased and he will consume more. The remaining future taxes to service and amortize the debt will paid by the people living after he has died.

But surely this won't matter, you might think, because the next generation will inherit the bonds as well as the tax liabilities that service them so that the amount paid in taxes will be exactly matched by the amount received in interest at every future date, regardless of who is living at the time. This is true, but since all individuals have finite lifespans, everyone will still have an incentive to consume more. They have more resources available for consumption now, and could care less whether future generations' tax liabilities are matched by interest earned on bonds. Consumption will be higher than otherwise, and investment and the future capital stock smaller, so the next generation will be clearly worse off.

Since the current generation has an incentive to consume more the IS curve will shift to the right and under fixed exchange rates the tax cut will be expansionary, Ricardian equivalence notwithstanding.

But there is a problem with this. As economist Robert Barro (1944- ) has pointed out, a large fraction of people deliberately leave inheritances to their children. During their lifetimes they will make a utility-maximizing decision as to how much of their incomes to consume and how much to plough into assets that will eventually be left to their children. When the government cuts taxes now and raises future taxes by an amount equal in present value, it shifts wealth to the current generation from its heirs, disturbing that equilibrium. The current generation is being induced to consume more, letting the next generation pay the interest and amortize the debt.

This is inconsistent, however, with the plans of the current generation to leave an inheritance to its children. Should not the reaction of private individuals currently living be to restore the integrity of their desired bequest to their children by simply saving the additional disposable income resulting from the tax cut to leave to their children to keep them as well off as before the tax cut? Why would there be any effect on current consumption?

But since the next generation receives the bonds as well as the future interest liabilities on them why should the current generation have to save the tax cut? It is true that the next generation will receive the bonds, but those bonds will not be received by the heirs of anyone who does not purchase them. By not buying bonds and by spending the tax cut, individuals currently living ensure that their heirs will not inherit bonds equal to their inherited future tax liability. By buying bonds with the receipts from the tax cut, on the other hand, each person now alive can guarantee that her heirs will receive an asset that will yield interest equal to the future taxes that will have to be paid to service the additional public debt resulting from the tax cut.

The argument that a tax cut will shift wealth from future generations to the present generation assumes that the current generation does not care about its children. The Ricardian Equivalence approach essentially regards the family tree as the unit of decision, not the current generation in that family tree. The individual will eventually die, but the family will continue forever. The utility of the family will be maximized by an optimal path of intergenerational consumption which the government cannot affect by adjusting the intergenerational timing of its taxation.

Obviously, however, not everyone will have heirs that he/she cares about. In that case any cut in taxes received late in life is an invitation to spend more and let other people's heirs pay the interest and amortize the debt in years to come. As a result, a cut in current taxes will have some intergenerational effect on current consumption, though not as much as might at first be supposed. This, of course, assumes that those of the current generation that care about their heirs do not reduce their current consumption enough, and pass on enough to future generations, to compensate their heirs for the fact that a fraction of the population, not having heirs, will consume the revenue from the current tax cut. The problem is that it will be difficult for those that have heirs they care about to figure out how much extra savings will be required to offset the additional current consumption of those who have no heirs they care about.

The Ricardian Equivalence argument also assumes that people know that a tax cut must be financed by higher future taxes. Surely, a major expansion of the government debt over a period of years will not go unnoticed, and people will implicitly realize that future taxes will have to be levied to service it. But a tax cut of a couple of hundred dollars in any given year may be hardly noticed. Disposable income will increase and the increase may be automatically spent. Tax cuts may therefore have some effect on consumption due to an misinformation-driven illusory wealth effect even if there is no actual effect on wealth.

The upshot of the discussion here and in the previous topic is that a tax cut will probably lead to an increase in consumption, though the magnitude of this increase will probably be smaller than envisaged in the simplistic Keynesian presentation.

It is time for a test. Be sure and think up your own answers to the questions before looking at the ones provided.

Question 1
Question 2
Question 3

Choose Another Topic in the Lesson